Fishermen Express Concerns in Washington Today; Catch Shares Can Help

Amanda Leland, EDF Oceans Program - National Policy Director

Amanda Leland, EDF Oceans Program - National Policy Director

Fishermen are here in Washington, D.C. this week to express their concerns with fisheries today—and they have good reason to be frustrated. Even after decades of regulations aimed at restoring fisheries big problems still exist.

Today over 60 federal fish stocks are overfished or have overfishing occurring, resulting in declining catches and shrinking revenues.  We must rebuild these fish populations to restore vibrant fishing communities, because economic recovery requires biological recovery.  But, the key is picking the path that makes common sense.  

Until recently, fishery managers didn’t see a good choice.  Controlling overfishing has usually meant shrinking fishing seasons or even implementing closures, approaches that have serious economic impacts. For example, in the New England groundfish fishery significant reductions in resource abundance, allowable catches, and the number of active vessels reduced total fishing days by about half between 1995 to 2008 (Green, 2009; Thunberg, NEFSC, pers. comm.).  Commercial and recreational fishermen in the Southeast U.S. are just beginning to feel the cost of a closure on red snapper.  If better management options don’t surface soon, these impacts are expected to continue for the foreseeable future and grow as other regional fisheries close down too.

In contrast, catch share management can deliver increased prosperity, sustainability, and flexibility.  Instead of pushing fishermen off the water to restore the red snapper fishery in the Gulf of Mexico, fishery managers worked with commercial fishermen to develop a catch share program, which has increased dock-side prices, decreased bycatch and helped end overfishing (Steele 2008).  Red snapper populations are now rebounding, meaning more fish for everyone, including recreational fishermen.  

In the commercial Alaska halibut fishery, catch share management has extended the fishing season from less than a week to more than eight months each year, allowing fishermen to have more full-time work as well as flexibility in deciding when to fish (NOAA Fisheries 2009).  These and other catch share programs stand out as the few bright spots in fisheries today. 

Transitioning to catch shares now is a necessary and worthwhile investment, because it can solve the overfishing problem, while boosting profits and improving jobs for fishermen.  In addition, over time catch shares can reduce and stabilize the overall federal investment needed to support fishing jobs: catch shares shift some management costs to fishermen once they are economically-viable again.  I believe there are solutions for recreational fishing too—solutions that help keep fishermen on the water through better scientific data and tools to make sure that the amount of fish caught stays within limits.

Fishermen continue to suffer from the collapse of fish stocks around the country.  Putting off rebuilding is not the answer as it only continues the downward spiral that has been putting people out of work for decades.  Instead Congress should invest in a durable solution that restores economic, cultural, and biological prosperity to our nation’s fishing communities.

Works Cited

Green, A. (2009, May 30). Move to redefine New England Fishing. The New York Times, pp. A18.

Fisheries of the Caribbean, Gulf of Mexico, and South Atlantic; Snapper Grouper Fishery of the South Atlantic; Red Snapper Closure. Federal Register Vol. 74 Issue. 232. 12/02/2009.

NOAA Fisheries Service. (2009). Catch Share Spotlight No. 1: Alaska IFQ Halibut and Sablefish Program.

Steele, Phil. (2008, November 17). An Overview of the Gulf of Mexico Red Snapper and Grouper/Tilefish IFQ Programs. Southeast Regional Office (SERO) National Marine Fisheries Services.

This entry was posted in Uncategorized and tagged , , , , . Bookmark the permalink. Both comments and trackbacks are currently closed.

2 Comments

  1. Posted February 24, 2010 at 12:42 pm | Permalink

    http://www.reel-time.com/articles/conservation/%E2%80%9Cunited-we-fish%E2%80%9D-or-united-we-overfish/

    “UNITED WE FISH”, OR UNITED WE OVERFISH?
    Feb 23rd, 2010 | By Capt. John McMurray | Category: Conservation
    What exactly are anglers marching for here?

    I’ve been trying to stay quiet on this “United we Fish” march that’s taking place in Washington DC this week. But frankly it’s annoying me to the point that I just can’t hold it in any longer. I’m all for anglers going down to DC and expressing their concerns. But I’d be lying if I didn’t say that it didn’t bother me greatly that anglers are going, literally by the busload, to join hands with a commercial fishing industry not known for its conservation ethic, in an effort to weaken some of the most important provisions of fishery management law .

    A little background here before I continue with what is my opinion, and my opinion alone (I’m not representing any group or organization I may be affiliated with or a member of).

    Current law rightly requires fishery managers to rebuild overfished stocks in a time period that is “as short as possible,” generally not to exceed 10 years (except in cases where the biology of the stock, other environmental conditions or international agreements dictate otherwise). By all means, reasonable.

    Congress, with what appeared to be overwhelming support from the American people, reaffirmed the need to rebuild overfished stocks promptly when it reauthorized the Magnuson-Stevens Act in 2006, upholding the timeframe first enacted in the Sustainable Fisheries Act amendments of 1996. Revised language in the reauthorization explicitly directed fishery management councils to heed the advice of independent scientists on their Science and Statistical Committees regarding the maximum harvest levels which will permit managers to rebuild fisheries on schedule.

    Such a change in the law was long sought by not only environmentalists but by conservation-minded angling groups, who argued that the provision was needed to alter the culture on regional fisheries management councils, which have a history of discounting scientific recommendations if the resultant economic pain threatened to be too great for their constituencies. In addition, the reauthorization required firm catch limits and accountability measures be established to ensure that such fisheries were rebuilt.

    In short, the 2006 Magnuson Act Reauthorization gives fishery management law real teeth and thus far it appears to be working. Rebuilding for most species is either done, or near completion.

    Unsurprisingly, because of firm time lines and rebuilding goals, there’s been some economic pain suffered not only by the commercial fishing industry, but the recreational fishing industry, as seasons and bag limits shrink and the stocks recover from decades of overfishing. A poor economy has exacerbated the situation. In response, each year since the Reauthorization, Rep. Frank Pallone (D-NJ) has introduced the “Flexibility in Rebuilding American Fisheries Act”. Last June, Sen. Charles Schumer (D-NY) introduced companion legislation in the Senate. As I understand it, the march in DC is essentially to show support for these two bills.

    At first glance flexibility in fisheries management may seem reasonable. If you allow some exemptions so that some stocks can rebuild in 15 or 20 years rather than 10, and the population remains on an upward trajectory the whole time with no overfishing, why not allow such exemptions so that folks are not hurt by restrictive measures? Unfortunately, it is not that simple. There is in fact great danger to adding such flexibility in current fishery management law. It would set us back decades, and would greatly benefit commercial fishermen while inevitably hurting anglers. Here’s why:

    First, the legislation changes language in the existing law from “as short as possible” to “as short as practicable.” This small alteration could greatly weaken Congress’ intent to require fishery managers to rebuild overfished stocks as quickly as possible and gives the Councils ample reason to procrastinate. The flexibility legislation’s wording is so ambiguous that I’d think it would be nearly impossible to implement any finite time frames for any fishery rebuilding schedule. The legislation would merely cloak delay in the euphemism “flexibility,” and would allow managers to avoid both lawsuits and the need to recover fish populations.

    Still, advocates of the Flexibility legislation continue to say that a 10-year rebuilding requirement is “arbitrary” and not science-based even when scientists clearly say such goals are indeed possible. And I suppose in the strictest sense, 10 years could be considered arbitrary. But any deadline could be so labeled. A 20-year timeline would be just as “arbitrary” as a 10-year one, and Council members, seeking to placate their constituents would be unlikely to work any harder to recover a stock in 20 or 30 years than in 10. And even after that, there’s no reason to believe managers would get serious about rebuilding and wouldn’t only ask for more flexibility down the road. Don’t know about you guys, but I’d like to see some of these fisheries rebuilt in my lifetime, which is already happening under current law!

    A good example is summer flounder, which ironically is the fish that began the “flexibility” movement. The species bottomed out in the late 1980s and early 1990s. Anglers, particularly those in my home state of New York, have had to make significant sacrifices, but as a result the stock has increased five-fold. Unpopular and painful as they may be, regulations have led to the expansion of the age and size structure. There is now an abundance of larger older fish, a big improvement over just a few years ago, when few fish survived past two years (14″) due to intense fishing pressure. This confirms how low this population was due to massive overfishing. Now, because of limits on overfishing, and adherence to a deadline for rebuilding, the stock is rebounding nicely. Summer flounder will likely be totally rebuilt by 2013.

    Moving on, the flexibility legislation also allows mangers to claim that the status of an overfished stock is beyond their control. This would enable NMFS to consider factors other than fishing when evaluating managers’ progress in achieving rebuilding targets. It’s very likely that virtually anything can and will be used as an excuse to justify failure to rebuild. As I mentioned in a prior blog, fishermen are notorious for trying to place blame for declining stocks elsewhere: placing fault on development, pollution, climate change etc. While these factors are certainly relevant, they do not justify continued overfishing. When fish populations face stress from environmental factors, it doesn’t make sense to continue to catch them faster than they can reproduce, yet fishermen routinely point to such problems, and try to use them as excuses for overfishing collapsed stocks.

    A really good example of this is southern winter flounder. In that case, fishermen conveniently overlooked the fact that fish were being caught at more than 250% of the sustainable rate, and blamed the species decline (it’s currently at 9% of target levels) on pollution, predators, habitat disruptions, global warming… in fact, just about anything besides themselves. The Atlantic States Marine Fisheries Commission responded predictably, cutting landings in state waters by less than half after peer-reviewed scientific advice indicated that, in order to recover the stock, all harvest should be prohibited (but thanks to the Magnuson Act, harvest in federal waters had been closed).

    The flexibility legislation would further allow managers to extend rebuilding for an overfished stock if it is caught with other stocks in a “stock complex”. This provision would delay indefinitely the rebuilding of one or more stocks in a multi-species fishery and allow fishermen to continue targeting healthier stocks at the expense of the overfished stock(s). The result – as seen in New England – is widespread overfishing of the weakest and most vulnerable stocks.

    Perhaps the most important provision in the bill is that it would allow managers to extend the 10-year timeline to “minimize economic impacts” if a stock is on an upward trend. Prior to 1996, fishery managers were able to put off rebuilding in the name of minimizing economic impacts, but such a policy has historically resulted in chronic overfishing. The longer the rebuilding period, the longer managers, under extreme pressure from their constituents and politicians, will put off rebuilding as the stocks remain at a low level.

    Historically, by granting extensions, special exceptions etc., managers have done nothing but create worsening situations. “Flexibility” really takes us back to pre-1996 fisheries management, when “optimum yield” was defined as “maximum sustainable yield adjusted” to allow for various considerations, including economic impact. In practice, quotas were always set well above Maximum Sustainable Yield to increase short-term profits, resulting in the collapse of New England groundfish stocks. It’s disturbing to see the recreational fishing industry trying to return to those old, discredited policies, which would return us to the failed management system that led Congress to enact the rebuilding provisions in the first place. And let’s not forget that overfishing has more severe economic consequences than regulations designed to ensure sustainable fishing. Rebuilding fish populations to healthy levels makes good economic sense.

    Yes, there are some teeth in the new Magnusson Act, which was authorized late in 2006 and yes, the regulations can really suck, especially if you are trying to run a charter business… But they are absolutely necessary if we want abundant and sustainable fisheries and the opportunity for the average-Joe to catch a fish rather than having to pay a professional to catch fish from a depleted stock. I can understand why commercial fishermen would adamantly disagree with me here, and I can understand the charter/party boat industry’s support of flexibility legalization, but I don’t get why any angler would want to go to DC to fight so that commercial interests can have greater flexibility to exploit a public fishery, and so make it harder for the average guy to find anything to catch.

    I get that there’s been plenty of recent anti-government populism due to recent restrictive measures and even closures. The recent black seabass shutdown in our region and some restrictive scup (porgy) regulations, combined with the tough but necessary measures we’ve had to endure to rebuild fluke by 2013 (and of course amberjack and red snapper in the South) have created more fear and loathing amongst anglers and renewed support for Flexibility legislation. And the folks working to advance public support for legislation are certainly fanning the flames. Yet interestingly enough the Pallone and Schumer bill would not do anything to address most if not all of these matters.

    Black sea bass and scup are both recovered stocks. In both cases restrictive regulations were the result of recreational overages. Nothing in the bill would have interfered with NMFS’ obligation to avoid overfishing (and thus the black sea bass closure would remain a valid measure), and the sea bass annual catch limit debate was resolved under current law. Similarly, the scup annual catch limit was established on a recovered stock–there was no question of the annual catch limit being established to meet a recovery deadline.

    In short, the bill won’t address most of the problems that the recreational fishing industry always seems to mention in the same breath as “flexibility”. It does nothing to fix MRFSS, would not affect the closures, would not address MPAs, etc. About the only fishery it would have much application to is fluke, and by this point in the recovery, and with the 2008 year class coming on strong, the affect there would be trivial. The only ones that will be helped by the bill will be the New England commercial groundfishermen and the southern snapper/grouper types. Certainly not worth going to DC for I’d think.

    My overarching point is this. Any student of fishery management can see that managers and fishermen have exploited every loophole they can to catch every last fish they can. While the reauthorization of the Magnuson Act late in 2006 closed some of the loopholes, it is clear that “flexibility” legislation would open up a whole slew of new ones. The temptation to push back rebuilding will perpetuate management based on politics rather than on science. These bills would, in effect, roll back the law to a time when fishery managers routinely placed short-term economic considerations over the long-term health of the fishery. We’ve tried “flexibility” all the way up to 1996 and it’s pretty clear, based on a history of overfishing, that it didn’t work. Flexibility was the problem back then and it’s certainly not the solution now.

    One would think that anglers would support the Magnuson Stevenson Act and allow rebuilding rules to work as intended to restore healthy fisheries as soon as possible. Going down to DC to hold hands with commercial fisherman in the fight to weaken the most important conservation provisions in fishery management law just seems so wrong on so many levels. Man I would like to see anglers traveling down to DC so that they can express their desire to conserve stocks of fish, rather than their desire to take more. Perhaps we should start to arrange that?

    ——————–

    Below, courteously of Charlie Witek, is an analysis of how such a flexibility bill could affect fish stocks in our region.

    BLACK SEA BASS: NO EFFECT. As black sea bass are already a “recovered” species, legislation that does nothing more than extend the rebuilding period/extend rebuilding would have no impact on current and future management. NMFS’ obligation to act to prevent overfishing would remain unchanged, so the October “emergency closure” would have been unaffected. The later debate over the Annual Catch Limit, which eventually saw the ACL raised to 3.7 million pounds, could be and was resolved under current law, and did not require “flexibility” legislation to accomplish.

    BLACKFISH: NO EFFECT. Managed by ASMFC, which is not bound by the terms of the Magnuson Act.

    BLUEFISH: NO EFFECT. Bluefish have been deemed recovered, making any change to the rebuilding period irrelevant.

    COD: REBUILDING PERIOD COULD BE EXTENDED, LIKELY TO THE DETRIMENT OF NEW YORK ANGLERS. Anglers currently may retain 10 fish, and are enjoying a resurgence of cod into waters easily accessible by New York boats, particularly those on the East End of Long Island. Extending the rebuilding period would have the effect of increasing the ACL, including commercial harvest, leaving fewer fish in the water than is currently the case. As New York is at the southern fringe of the cod’s range, its fishery appears to be dependent on a population large enough to leave its core New England range and expand into waters closer to New York. Increased commercial harvest would make such expansion less likely, and increase the pressure that commercial vessels would put on the fish in the Block Island area. Thus, while “flexibility” legislation might increase the overall ACL, it could easily result in fewer cod being available to New York anglers, and actually reduce recreational harvest.

    SCUP: NO EFFECT. Scup are rebuilt, and thus the delayed rebuilding permitted by the proposed “flexibility” language would have no effect. However, overfishing is still prohibited, so the 2010 ACL established by the Mid-Atlantic Fishery Management Council, even if smaller than strictly necessary (which I suspect to be the case) would not be affected, nor would future increases in the ACL be facilitated, by adoption of the legislation. The only certain way to ease recreational scup limits is to increase the recreational allocation from the current 21% of ACL.

    STRIPED BASS: NO EFFECT. Striped Bass are managed by ASMFC, which is not bound by the terms of the Magnuson Act.

    SUMMER FLOUNDER: REBUILDING PERIOD COULD BE EXTENDED, WITH DEBATABLE BENEFITS. This is arguably the species which launched the “flexibility” movement. However, we are at the stage in the restoration of the stock where the benefits of extension may be moot. With only three years to go in the rebuilding process, and with the largest year class in 26 years having been spawned in 2008 (which will begin to recruit into the commercial fishery this year and into the recreational fishery in 2011—although later in New York given our highest-on-the-coast minimum size), the full recovery of summer flounder by 2013 is likely a done deal. That is when the real discontent will set in, as anglers realize that the effect of the 2008 stock assessment, which lowered the estimate of stock productivity substantially, will be to permanently freeze limits at restrictive levels. The long-term answer to relief for coastal anglers lies in the reallocation of the overall ACL. For New York anglers, it lies in abandoning the current state allocations, which are based on a single year of MRFSS data (1998), and probably do not reflect the current summer distribution of the species, in favor of either coastwide regulations or a new set of state allocations which reflect the realities of today’s fishery, rather than those of a decade ago. “Flexibility” legislation will do nothing to relieve either the inter-sector or the inter-state imbalances which currently plague New York’s anglers.

    WEAKFISH: NO EFFECT. Weakfish are managed by ASMFC, which is not bound by the terms of the Magnuson Act.

    WINTER FLOUNDER: RECOVERY COULD BE DELAYED INDEFINITELY, SO THAT STOCKS NEVER RISE ABOVE CURRENT LEVELS; LOCAL EXTIRPATION IS POSSIBLE. Passage of “flexibility” legislation might well be the final nail in the flounder’s coffin or, at least, in the flounder’s recovery. Section 2(1)(B)(ii)(II) of the bill would permit the rebuilding period to be extended if the agency finds that the “cause of the fishery decline is outside the jurisdiction of the Council or the rebuilding program cannot be effective only by limiting fishing activities.” In the case of this particular provision, there is no restriction on how far out the rebuilding deadline might be set. Thus, if the New England Fishery Management Council, which has a history of denying fisheries problems and of attributing problems to causes other than fishing, were to determine that the winter flounder’s decline was due to pollution, shoreline hardening, dredging, predation, or even overfishing in state waters, which are outside of the Council’s jurisdiction, it could invoke this provision and use it to indefinitely delay the flounder’s recovery. Given the dire condition of the flounder stock—just 9% of the biomass target—combined with unavoidable scientific uncertainty and the fact that the stock is comprised of local subpopulations of greater or lesser degrees of vulnerability, failure to make a serious effort to recover the species by a date certain is likely to result in the permanent loss of local populations. Such loss, or even the failure to take meaningful measures to recover the stock, would not be of long-term benefit to New York’s anglers.

  2. Posted March 9, 2010 at 5:45 pm | Permalink

    Nobody should be surprised at the extent of corporate power in our government, or corporate influence over our laws, policies, and actions. Large corporations began their ascension toward omnipotence in the United States just after the civil war, which was fought, in large part, over the issue of slavery. Shortly after the war, the Fourteenth Amendment was added to the U.S. Constitution for the purpose of finally guaranteeing that at all people (even black people) were to be treated equally, and that the federal government could not interfere with an individual’s (even a black individual) pursuit of life, liberty, or pursuit of happiness.
    The Supreme Court ruled in the Civil Rights Cases (1883), that the Fourteenth Amendment applied only to the actions of government, not to those of private individuals, and consequently did not protect persons against individuals or private entities (such as large corporations) who violated their civil rights. Even then corporate attorneys were clever. Within just a few years the U.S. Supreme Court decided Santa Clara County v. Southern Pacific Railroad Company (1886), and issued the farthest reaching dicta ever. The Court pronounced that Corporations were forevermore to be legally treated as individuals and afforded protection under the Fourteenth amendment.
    Interestingly, the Supreme Court decided later in Plessy v. Ferguson, (1896) that blacks could be treated differently, which helped to ensure cheap labor would be available to be used with the newfound status of “individual” to promote the unprecedented growth of corporate power and influence in the United States.
    That power, fostered and coddled as it has been, has grown to the extent that individuals within major corporations regularly decide that it is cost effective for the corporation to act immorally or even illegally. The individuals operating corporations were absolved from personal liability of any kind as long as what they do is in the best interest in the corporation. This is consistent with Adam Smiths’ illumination in the Wealth of Nations: when ownership is separated from management, the latter will inevitably begin to neglect the interests of the former.
    Catch shares allow for corporate ownership of Alaska’s Fish, and catch shares are heavily backed by corporate interests. Catch shares are touted as a “management” scheme promulgated under the authority of the Magnuson Act by the Secretary of Commerce, but actually separate ownership from management. The goal of the Magnuson Act is to provide for fishery management plans that ensure optimum yields from the fishery resources of the United States. It is supposed to be a scheme lessening the impact on fishing communities – “a fishing community is a social or economic group whose members reside in a specific location and share a common dependency on commercial, recreational, or subsistence fishing or on directly related fisheries-dependent services and industries.” 50 CFR § 600.345 2(b) But catch shares eliminate communities and fisherman from the equation.
    Catch Shares aren’t a management plan; catch shares simply provide for private ownership over resources formerly considered Public. That is, the vessel owners and lessees who were awarded catch shares now have a legally protectable interest that can be bought and sold to any individual. But their ownership interests are in no way necessarily linked to actual management of a fishery; a per vessel allotment functions the same way without permanently relinquishing rights to resources. Under the scheme, certain canneries were also awarded exclusive and permanent rights to process the fish.
    Ironically, prior to the creation of catch shares fisherman had no “legally protectable interest” in the fish they caught and sold. See, Alliance Against IFQ’s, 84 F.3d at 352 (quoting Lujan v. Defenders of Wildlife, 504 U.S. 555, 560 (1992)).
    One might be tempted to ask, if catch shares aren’t a bonafide fisheries management tool, but merely function to allocate private ownership where none existed before, then where did the idea originate, and who is promoting it? One thing is certain, it wasn’t thought up by a fisheries biologist looking to “ensure optimum yields from the fishery resources of the United States” as required by the Magnuson Act. It is a safe bet that it was conceived by someone who stood to profit from it, and it is certainly true that corporate “individuals” who stand to benefit a great deal from catch shares continue invest heavily in their continuation and further implementation.
    The Environmental Defense Fund, for example is a huge backer that is politically well-connected enough to influence policy not only in the senate halls, but also at federal agencies such as NOAA. The EDF regularly is mentioned in newsprint as a voice in support of catch shares, a voice in opposition to commercial fisherman and fishing communities. The name EDF implies environmental concern – even activism. But in reality the EDF is Walmart and a few other gigantic corporate interests, which have now infiltrated the highest levels of government – the heads of both NMFS and NOAA are both former officers of the corporate backed EDF.
    Jane Lubchenco was vice chairwoman of the EDF board before her being selected by President Obama to head NOAA. Patricia Kurkal (NMFS Regional Administrator) and the fresh-faced Amanda Leland (EDF Spokesperson) are but two more heads on the Hydra that is the Walmart backed EDF. They espouse corporate backed opinions as if they are their own, and as if they are based upon science, or even actual environmental concerns. Having been appointed by Obama, Lubchenco is now shameless in her support of catch shares and has made no public effort to reconcile her former position with EDF and her duties with NOAA. The “catch share” term comes from the Environmental Defense Fund, and is used regularly by Lubchenco, who, after her Senate confirmation, immediately challenged the New England council to complete work on its catch share system.
    Lubchenco was as a witness for the first of two congressional field hearings on federal fisheries law enforcement failings identified by the U.S. Commerce Department. When asked to define a “catch share,” Lubchenco replied that a catch share was “a negotiable stock that fishermen can sell as they go out of business, allowing them to exit with some cash.” The subtext: catch shares are a mechanism specifically designed and employed to ensure that corporate individuals like Walmart own all fisheries resources in the future. Catch shares are, and are designed to be the death knell of fisherman and fishing communities.
    By Lubchenco’s admission, catch shares have nothing to do with fisheries management, and were created by the EDF (Walmart) as a way to take over the harvesting, processing, sales and marketing of all fisheries resources.
    Coming full circle, one thing we can all learn from the earlier discussed court cases is that our voice counts, and it counts every step of the way. We can, if we work at it, change this policy of privatization. We can refuse to have our livelihoods taken for corporate use. When the head of NOAA is such an obvious pawn for the interests of Walmart, we can refuse to be duped and demand our government respond to our needs. It starts with our local governments and extends to the highest levels of elected government, including the President of the United States. You, I, we need to ensure our voice is heard. We’re not all drawing checks from Walmart yet, so it isn’t too late. If we can’t force people like Leland, Lubchenco, and Kurkal to publicly qualify their statements as being EDF propaganda, we can force are elected representatives to take notice and begin working exclusively in the interests of the people, starting with fisherman and fishing communities as defined and mandated by federal law.
    The email list for Alsaka State Senators is: Senator_Con_Bunde@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_John_Cowdery@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Bettye_Davis@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Fred_Dyson@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Johnny_Ellis@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Kim_Elton@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Hollis_French@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Lyda_Green@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Gretchen_Guess@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Lyman_Hoffman@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Charlie_Huggins@legis.state.ak.us,Representative_Albert_Kookesh@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Donny_Olson@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Ralph_Seekins@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Bert_Stedman@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Ben_Stevens@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Gary_Stevens@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Gene_Therriault@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Thomas_Wagoner@legis.state.ak.us,Senator_Gary_Wilken@legis.state.ak.us
    The Federal Email list is:
    Senator Mark Begich – senator@begich.senate.gov
    Senator Lisa Murkowski – http://murkowski.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?p=EMailLisa
    Congressman Don Young – https://donyoung.house.gov/Contact/ContactForm.htm?Zip5=99901
    In Alaska, other appropriate representatives are:
    Governor Sean Parnell
    Juneau Office
    Alaska State Capitol Building
    Third Floor
    Mailing Address:
    P.O. Box 110001
    Juneau, AK 99811-0001
    Telephone Inquiries:
    Phone (907) 465-3500
    Fax (907) 465-3532
    Anchorage Office
    550 West 7th Avenue, Suite 1700
    Anchorage, AK 99501
    Phone (907) 269-7450
    Fax (907) 269-7461
    Washington DC Office
    444 North Capitol NW, Suite 336
    Washington, DC 20001-1512
    Phone (202) 624-5858
    Fax (202) 624-5857
    Fairbanks Office
    675 7th Avenue, Suite H5
    Fairbanks, AK 99701-4596
    Phone (907) 451-2920
    Fax (907) 451-2858
    U.S. Senator Lisa Murkowski:
    709 Hart Senate Building
    Washington, D.C. 20510
    Main: 202-224-6665
    Fax: 202-224-5301
    510 L Street
    Suite 550
    Anchorage, AK 99501
    Main: 907-271-3735
    Fax: 907-276-4081
    Toll Free: 1-877-829-6030
    Congressman Don Young
    WASHINGTON, DC OFFICE
    Office of Congressman Don Young
    2111 Rayburn House Office Building
    Washington, DC 20515
    T (202) 225-5765 F (202) 225-0425
    ANCHORAGE DISTRICT OFFICE
    Peterson Tower Building
    510 L St, Suite 580
    Anchorage, AK 99501-1954
    T (907) 271-5978 F (907) 271-5950
    FAIRBANKS FIELD OFFICE
    Office of Congressman Don Young
    101 12th Avenue, # 10
    Fairbanks, AK 99701-6275
    T (907) 456-0210 F (907) 456-0279
    JUNEAU FIELD OFFICE
    612 W. Willoughby Avenue, Suite B
    P.O. Box 21247
    Juneau, Alaska 99802
    T (907) 586-7400 F (907) 586-8922
    KENAI FIELD OFFICE
    805 Frontage Road, Suite 110
    Kenai, Alaska 99611
    T (907) 283-7701
    AK Senator Mark Begich
    WASHINGTON, DC OFFICE
    144 Russell Senate Office Building
    Washington, DC 20510
    phone. (202) 224-3004
    toll free. (877) 501 – 6275
    fax. (202) 224-2354
    ANCHORAGE DISTRICT OFFICE
    Peterson Tower, Suite 750
    510 L St
    Anchorage, AK, 99501
    phone. (907) 271 – 5915
    toll free. (877) 501 – 6275*
    fax. (907) 258 – 9305
    FAIRBANKS FIELD OFFICE
    101 12th Ave, Room 206
    Fairbanks, AK 99701
    phone. (907) 456-0261
    toll free. (877) 501 – 6275*
    fax. (907) 451-7290
    JUNEAU FIELD OFFICE
    One Sealaska Plaza, Suite 308
    P.O. Box 21850
    Juneau, AK 99802
    phone. (907) 586 – 7700
    toll free. (877) 501 – 6275
    fax. (907) 586 – 7702